Electricity Pricing and Availability Based Tariff for Competitive Electricity Markets
Electricity Pricing and
Availability Based Tariff
for Competitive electricity markets [1]
Prof. V
Ranganathan.
Professor (Retd.), IIM, Bangalore.
Until recently electricity industry throughout the world was
a regulated integrated natural monopoly[2],
with generation, transmission and distribution being vertically integrated[3]. The industry was restructured in many
advanced countries, US, UK, Europe, Australia and also later in developing
countries like India, Pakistan, Nepal, Thailand etc. Competition was the reason for restructuring
in the US, where there was a big price gap between States, and the customers in
high priced States wanted to shop around for electricity from low priced
States, by having wholesale competition through open access. At that time, the gain to customers and
efficient producers and the loss to inefficient producers was estimated to be
$100 billion, which was the motive force for restructuring.[4] In UK, the driving force was the conviction
that business is not the business of the Government, and the consequent
privatization drive started with Ms. Margaret Thatcher, beginning with
privatization of coal mines, when the miners went on a strike and took the
country to ransom. In India, the motivation
for reforms was the funds crunch.
During the time of Mr.Arif Mohamed Khan as the Power Minister, CEA made
the forecast that for the next year the incremental demand would be 50 GW,
against the existing capacity for the previous 30 years of only 50 GW. The Government approached the World Bank for
funding this expansion, for which the World Bank put the condition that the
country should undertake Power Sector Reform.
Coincidentally, the World Bank itself was being questioned by the US
appointed Meltzer Commission, for its role in duplicating the work of capital
markets, instead of sticking to its original mandate of ‘removing
poverty’. The operational significance
of this criticism was that the World Bank should stop funding power sector
hardware by lending for power stations by NTPC etc., and should focus on
funding ‘reform studies’.
Notwithstanding the different foci for restructuring in
different countries, introduction of competitive markets in electricity became a central
theme not only in the US, but also in UK, Australia etc. The main themes were, unbundling the industry
into its segments, generation, transmission and distribution, deregulating
generation which became amenable to competition and regulating transmission and
distribution which were still natural monopolies. The World Bank coined two terminologies, one
for the developed world and one for the developing, viz. competition in the market for the West and
competition for the market for
developing countries. The former was
multiple suppliers quoting hourly or half hourly prices for their generation
and bidding to the pool or independent system operator; the latter was ‘competitive bidding’ as in
India, to supply electricity at fixed price for the next 25 years.
Competition
meant that generators could supply to any big customer or utility in any State
and similarly the distribution utilities or big customers can buy from any
generator or supplier (wholesale competition).
This required the legislative measure of introducing ‘compulsory
nondiscriminatory open access’ in transmission.
Along with this, the transmission pricing had to be reworked, because in
the days of integrated monopoly, all the costs of generation, transmission and
distribution were embedded in one price.
The simplest form of transmission pricing was the postage stamp
pricing. A postage stamp rate is a fixed
charge per unit of energy transmitted over a zone, irrespective of the distance
within the zone. For transmitting power
across zones, the price corresponding to every zone was added, and this process
was called ‘pancaking’. Postage stamp
rates are based on average system costs, and may be either cents per kwh or
cents per kw or a combination of both energy and capacity charges. The charges can vary with peak- off-peak,
week day and week-end, firm vs nonfarm transport of electricity etc.
Traditional transmission pricing was based on ‘contract path’, from a point A to B,
along a transmission line, so constructed for that purpose. Contract path pricing may be agreed by
participants to minimize transmission charges and avoid ‘pancaking’. However, as WW Hogan[i]
argued contract path is a fiction, and does not reflect actual flow of power,
which is determined by Kirchoff’s law, and flows into a network. He suggested ‘nodal
pricing’, which is the difference between the prices of electricity at 2 nodes
in different locations, since the cost of transmission will then equilibriate
the two prices. If the price of power in
Chukka (in Sikkim) is Rs.1 per kwh and in Bangalore it is Rs.3 per kwh, then
the transmission cost between Chukka and Bangalore should be Rs.2 per kwh. Another variant is flow based pricing, viz. dollars per MW-km; where the price depends on the quantity of
power transported and the distance. A
third variant is ‘congestion pricing’, where
the price increases with congestion, based on the principle that whoever has
the maximum willingness to pay, must be allowed to transport first in order to
use the transmission capacity efficiently.
It is much like the dynamic pricing practiced in the airlines, where you
always have a seat, even at the last minute, but at a high price. However, unlike the airlines’ dynamic
pricing, congestion costs can be assigned either to the marginal user, or can
be shared with all existing users, as it will indicate the need for adding
another line to transport electricity, wherever there is congestion. When the transmission becomes congested so
that no more power can be transmitted from say Eastern region to Southern
region, more expensive generation may have to operate in Bangalore in South
than a pithead mine in Orissa. In a
competitive market, regardless of the form of transmission pricing used, this
would create a difference in the generation prices between the pithead mine in Orissa
and a load centre station in Bangalore.
(The Central Electricity Authority had long established that carrying
electricity through transmission lines is much cheaper than carrying coal
through Railways.) The difference
between these prices is the ‘economic price of transmission’. It reflects the costs of congestion and
losses. In the absence of congestion
pricing for transmission service, these ‘economic rents’ would represent a
windfall gain to the generation suppliers who are able to sell through the
congested interconnection. The
congestion revenues can be allocated to market participants through reduced
access fees etc.
In India, the Electricity Act (2003) brought ‘compulsory
nondiscriminatory open access’ for transmission, but competition was blunted by
the retrograde ‘open access surcharge’ on the one hand and pancaking and
arbitrarily high wheeling charges designed to protect inefficient State
Electricity Boards, by the State Electricity Regulators, who were captured by
the utilities they regulated. In fact,
before the advent of the regulators, the transmission cost was just to
compensate for the transmission losses, since transmission investment was
completely decoupled from transmission pricing. The CEA would identify weak links and would
augment transmission, subject to availability of funds. This had resulted in most of funds going for
generation and transmission getting very little investment. Even when transmission got funds, it was
frittered away in inessentials like telemetry, SCADA etc. Today the new mantra is ‘smart grid’ which
enables time-of-day pricing etc., but at present the first priority is removal
of congestion and enabling power to flow, i.e. sticking to the basics of
transmission line laying. Even now, the
national grid is not fully integrated, and we have two grids operating
asynchronously, the southern grid and the rest of india grid. The only gainers of these deficiencies are 3
entities in India, the Power Trading Corporation, The Indian Energy Exchange
IEX, and Power Exchange India Ltd., PXIL, who gain out of arbitrage
opportunities. At present we have
Eastern region surplus and the remaining regions deficit and there is a lot of
congestion due to absence of transmission lines to evacuate power from
Bramhaputra basin, Nepal, Bhutan etc.
Before the advent of Availability
Based Tariff introduced by the CERC, the situation was far worse, with
rampant grid indiscipline and States waylaying power meant for other
States. In order to overcome this
indiscipline, the high voltage point to point d.c. transmission was installed,
which enabled transfer of power from generation station to beneficiary State
directly on a point to point basis. This
was obviously an infructuous expenditure in a resource constrained economy,
just like the investments in standby diesel sets are today. The ABT came as a big game changer in this
circumstance.
ABT divided the power flow into two parts: a scheduled part
and an unscheduled part. The scheduled
part had a capacity charge and an energy charge. The capacity charge was to reimburse fixed
cost of plant, linked to plant’s declared capacity to supply MWs to the
generating station; to the receiving
State, it was proportional to the State’s share in the declared output for the
day, of the plant. The energy chare was
to reimburse the fuel cost of scheduled generation. The excess drawal of the States were priced
in a third category of UI (Unscheduled
Interchange) Charges, set much higher during periods of deviations below
the standard frequency of 50 Hz, and
very little incentives for generators who produce excessively during unwanted
periods, when the system frequency shot up above 50 Hz. The ABT is explained with great clarity by
Bhanu Bhushan in a primer on ABT[ii].
Process of ABT: Central Generating Stations indicate
their next day output capability to RLDC (G1, G2, G3). RLDC translates these into States’
entitlements according to their share (based on a modified Gadgil formula,
which gives a greater share to the State where the plant is located, and a
lesser but equal share to all other States in the region) (E1, E2, E3), and
communicates them to SLDCs. The SLDCs
convert them into their requirements (R1, R2, R3: Ri <= Ei). These are then transformed into Dispatch for
the CGSs as (D1, D2, D3) and as drawal limits for receiving States (d1, d2,
d3). Each CGS’s marginal generation
cost corresponds to a certain grid frequency for which it is equal to the UI
rate. When the grid frequency is lower
than this, it has all the incentive to operate at 100% of its capacity. When the grid frequency is higher than this
critical frequency, that plant can back down and save the marginal cost of
generation, and instead buy from the grid since that cost is lower. Thus it leads to merit order operation of
plants, and settling down at a grid frequency level corresponding to optimal
loading, given the capacities of the plants.
Of course, storage hydro operation is more complicated: there the objective is that (i) energy
storage capacity must be fully utilized over the year (ii) it should be
operated so as to replace the costliest source of other energy. Henry Jacoby has suggested a trick of using
an inverted demand duration curve to place the merit order position of hydro
satisfying the above two constraints[iii].
The ABT, and more particularly its third component of UI
charge, has significantly reduced grid indiscipline, by imposing fine on errant
States. However, certain problems
remain. Hydro power is a State resource
and the previous Electricity Act had kept the pricing of hydro power in the
jurisdiction of the State, and rightly so, keeping the federal structure of
India, in place. Thus hydro operation is
exogenous to ABT rules, and may bring in some asymmetry, particularly in the
light of generation incentives. (Can the
States decrease their hydro generation and increase their thermal portfolio, to
claim incentives?). In UK when this
advance declaration a day ahead was introduced, generators could game the
system by mothballing, viz. declaring a capacity unavailable as under
maintenance, and bringing it on the day of demand claiming a higher price for
it. Such abuses, one suspects, are available to Indian generators as
well. Most importantly ABT does not give
signals for increasing generation capacity, in fact, probably does the
opposite, by increasing grid frequency and lowering payment, when capacity is
augmented. This is similar to the
problem UK had when the regulator had given a capacity payment to all the
generators who were called in to supply, and who had bid lower than or equal to
the system marginal cost. Though the
capacity payment was based on the shadow price of power and was equal to the
loss of load probability and the value of loss of load, the generators had to
calculate when it will increase their payment if they added capacity and when
it will decrease it, by reducing lolp.
The final drawback is that the UI charges are determined by
the regulator and not market determined, nor is a method suggested whereby the
UI charges set by the regulator will serve as initial conditions and the system
will move to a different set of values based on overall supply and demand. Thus it fails critically to meet the
condition of competitive supply, which means supply = demand.
India has 3 power trading houses, one in public sector and
two in private sector. The total amount
of power traded is a very small quantity about 1-2% of total power
generated; Average price in 2008 was
around Rs.7.5 per kwh and maximum price Rs.11 per kwh. The public sector PTC had a margin of Rs.3
per kwh (too high!), but a gross profit of only 2% of the turn over of
Rs.88,687 million, for trading on 28,597 MU in 2012-13. The CMD and Board members who were mostly
Government IRS bureaucrats gave themselves hefty salaries of upto Rs.1 crore
per year, merely for milking the arbitrage opportunities. IEX, headed by retired IAS, had a margin of
5.2 paise per kwh in 2013-14, but had a profit before tax of 87% on turnover on
trading 29,270 MU of energy, showing a much slimmer organization. The third exchange, PXIL which was formed
with NSE and NCDEX, does not have its annual accounts on its website. It is worthwhile to point out, none of
these 3 exchanges have brought in competition;
they have been the beneficiaries
of the overall shortage of power and the consequent arbitrage
opportunities.
Conclusion: With the arrival of private sector in
power generation, the generation industry moved on from engineers to financial
engineers. Yet, sufficient generation
has not been forthcoming because transmission and distribution are still
regulated, and the regulators are more mindful of tariff shock, than in
incentivizing adequate supply of electricity.
This has lead to lot of investment that has gone into generation, not
being able to deliver the power. Reform
of transmission is most vital to give signals for competitive markets in
electricity to emerge. For that to
happen, the transmission and distribution reforms should take place, and the
engineers must be working alongside financial economists. Merely, bringing engineers and stock exchange
people, will not do.
[1]
Paper presented at the National Conference on Power Transmission and
Distribution, Bhopal on 22-23, Sept. 2014 by Indian Power Management Academy.
[2] A
natural monopoly is one where a single firm alone can produce at the minimum
cost. Typically this was due to
economies of scale—the feature of long run average cost declining with
output—through this was a sufficient but not necessary condition for a natural
monopoly.
[3]
Vertical integration is being integrated along the value chain; horizontal integration means integration
among different geographical areas.
[4] Estimated by Prof. Paul Joskow, MIT.
[i] WW
Hogan “Contract networks for competition in transmission grids” IAEE, 15th
Annual International Conference, Plenary paper, Tours, France, 18-20 May, 1992.
[ii]
Bhanu Bhushan “ABC of ABT: A primer on Availability Tariff” 27 June 2005
[iii]
Turvey and Anderson “Electricity Economics” World Bank., chapter 13.
ReplyDeleteI think that is one of the most significant info for me. And i am happy studying your article. But should commentary on some basic issues, The site taste is ideal, the articles is actually great : D. Just right job, cheers sign in hotmail
The following table shows locally available home loan rates which you can use to help calculate your monthly home loan instalments. canada mortgage calculator We start the calculator by outlining the four most popular options for advance payment scenarios, but you might be not tied to those options. mortgage calculator
ReplyDeleteThis information is very interesting. I like your blog because the content was really impressive.Thank you for giving much of information. compare energy retailers
ReplyDelete